The Impact of Macroeconomic Policies
Policy packages
Macroeconomic policies affect the economy in different ways and the outcome depends greatly on the state of the economy at the time of implementation. Most macroeconomic problems require a policy package that includes a range of different measures. You should be able to identify the economic and political objectives that trigger policy change and to evaluate the likely effectiveness of specific policies in relation to the relevant objective.
Most economic strategies require a combination of policies. This will depend on the time lags (i.e. time each policy takes to produce results) and on the political issues of that moment in time. As the case study testified, the economy was fairly stable in 1997. The then Chancellor, Gordon Brown, took advantage of this to introduce a new way of determining monetary policy by making The Bank of England independent and responsible for the inflation target (MPC). The aim was that this would make accelerating inflation less likely in the future. It also removed politics from monetary policy, eliminating the ability of a Chancellor to drop interest rates just before a general election…
A recessionary policy packages
Fast-forward to 2010, and post GFC (which the Labour government were accredited with purely down to the fact that they were in power, irrespective of the fact that it was America’s fault!). A coalition Conservative & Liberal Democrat government were elected.
Think about what their solution for the resulting GFC recession was. What policies did they have? Do you pay attention to current affairs? It is essential for success in this subject!
__Key Concepts: __
-
Bail out the banks.
-
Keep IR at 0.5% - E policy.
-
Cut the budget deficit, reduced to zero by 2020. Austerity! – C policy.
-
Nearly 1 million people in the public sector were made redundant – C policy.
-
[He believed austerity budgets would not have a negative multiplier effect – he was wrong! It stifled growth!].
-
‘Smaller government’ – significant for all free market thinkers, lower taxes (E policy) and limited public services (supply-side policy).
Osborne was obsessed with balancing the books – he wanted to cut the budget deficit(?) in order to start to tackle the national debt(?), or “fix the roof whilst the sun shines” as he famously put it. In the aftermath of the GFC public spending rose above 45% of GDP in order to nationalise the struggling banks.
By the time Osborne departed from government in 2016 it had fallen to 39% so arguably he was on course to have a budget surplus by 2020. The government’s role in the economy was substantially smaller. Post Brexit, May has changed focus and might need to provide government spending as an injection to our economy. So is that the end of austerity? For now perhaps.
Was there an alternative?
Many an economist would argue that austerity caused a much longer recession than necessary. Up to 2013, the economy remained sluggish and fell back into negative growth territory for one quarter (thus it was not a recession or ‘double dip’ as was feared at the time – but it came close!). Then, suddenly, in 2014 we registered annual growth of 3.2% for the year – the fastest growing economy in the EU! Was the ‘sluggish austerity’ years really necessary?
An alternative policy would have involved avoiding government spending cuts and shrinking public services, a Kenysian spending stimulus to the economy. There would have been an earlier return to growth, with higher tax revenues funding the spending and still the need to cut welfare payments to find the cash. This would in turn helped to reduce the public sector deficit.
If money had been channelled towards building infrastructure (perhaps via PFI/PPP initiatives), economic growth would have been even stronger and unemployment would have fallen faster.
Reflection time: What would you have done if you were Chancellor of the Exchequer in 2010? Would your policy package differ to Mr Osborne’s? If so, why?
Other aspects of economic policy
So far the focus has been upon conventional fiscal, monetary and supply-side policies and their effect on economic growth. There are other policies and perspectives to appreciate as well.
Automatic stabilisers can work to reduce the impact of the economic cycle without any change in policy. As U/E rises, government expenditure rises to cover the cost of benefits. Tax payments fall because incomes are falling. If we envision the C.F.I, this provides an instant increase in injections and decrease in leakages that will stimulate the economy or at least reduce the impact of recession. The reverse happens (gov spending reduced and taxes rise) as the economy recovers and these ‘automatic stabilisers’ should dampen the effect of a developing boom.
The policy package chosen by the government will depend partly on political preferences, but it will also be affected by many other influences (see below).
-
Changing technologies
-
Reactions to inequality
-
Globalisation
-
Vested interests
-
Climate change
Criteria for success and evaluating effectiveness
Some ‘success criteria’ for any government’s macroeconomic policy package success rate:
-
Policy objectives been met? Criteria should be SMART – e.g. did austerity reduce the deficit? Yes it did, by 35%.
-
Consequences that the policy has created?
-
Impact on economy as a whole?
-
Impact on specific groups of people within the population?
-
Unintended consequences? Government failure?
-
[Unexpected shocks/events need to be taken into account, as do policy trade-offs]
Evaluation has a tendency to reflect political preferences. Any good economist will look closely at the evidence and work out the implications without drawing on their personal political position! This combination of political/economic issues may derail a policy that when formulated, looked sensible.
Reflection Time: evaluate the effectiveness of post-BREXIT economic policies (namely drop IR to 0.25%, tax cuts to stimulate growth and abandoning any ‘budget surplus’ plan).
A summary of the different approaches
Keynesian policy - intervention: Keynes believed in the ‘animal forces’ that required government intervention (expansionary policy stoked by government spending) to boost economic growth. His belief has been adapted by the western world since WW2 – thus the mountains of national debt!
Monetarist policies - the Free Market: Hayek believed in the free market and the ‘invisible hand’ of demand/supply – that organic growth via sustainable banking and stable monetary policy would be a more sustainable growth model
Austerity policies: Used in times when national debt becomes a worry, cutbacks to manage the books and reset the sustainability of national debt.
Comparing alternative approaches
Throughout UK political history, contrasting theories have influenced policy making. Keynes dominated policy making from the 1940s to 1970s. With the election of Thatcher in 1979, there was a movement towards ‘the monetarist approach’ based on the work of Milton Friedman and other free market economists. Since the 1990s, policies have been drawn from both approaches. Current policies are clouded with uncertainty as we await the ‘Article 50 withdrawal’ from the EU.
Exam style question
Battle between Economic Policies
In the recent mid-term elections in America, the Democratic Party took a battering. But not in Minnesota. In 2010 Democrat Mark Dayton won the Governorship by a whisker from the Republicans who had been running the State government for the previous eight years. In 2014 Dayton’s majority was so clearcut that his Republican challenger conceded defeat before midnight. On a night of disaster for his party, Democrat Dayton won by a landslide in Minnesota.
Politically that may be a puzzle, but the economics are clearer. In October 2014 unemployment in Minnesota was 3.9%, one of the lowest figures in the country. When Dayton became Governor in 2010, unemployment in Minnesota had been 7.1%*. This was the result of higher economic growth in Minnesota compared with elsewhere. In particular, Minnesota had done notably better than its neighbour Wisconsin. In 2013, Wisconsin economic growth had been 1.7% compared with 2.8% in Minnesota. So how had this been achieved? *See the Table below.
Data from US Labour Bureau | Minnesota | Wisconsin | National USA |
Unemployment Oct 2010 | 7.1% | 8.0% | 9.8% |
Unemployment Oct 2014 | 3.9% | 5.4% | 5.8% |
% change | - 45% | - 32.5% | - 41% |
Minnesota and Wisconsin sit next to each other on the southern shores of the Great Lakes, i.e. on the border with Canada. Dayton won the governorship in 2010 with a policy of increased minimum wage, higher taxes on high income earners, and higher public spending in the poorer districts of the State. And that’s what he did. After a battle with Republicans he brought in the higher taxes in early 2013. The minimum wage rises began in August 2014 at $8 an hour, and will rise to $9 in 2015 and $9.50 in 2016. The public spending increases over the 4 years reached $2.1 billion.
By contrast, in Wisconsin the Republican governor followed a policy of austerity. Public spending was cut by £2 billion and there was no movement on the minimum wage. In Wisconsin the minimum wage remains $7.25, with no plan to increase it. As a publicity stunt before the mid-term elections, trade unions declared that they would sue governor Scott Walker, to force him to increase the minimum wage. Free market business magazine Forbes ran an article condemning ‘such a self-defeating approach’.
The reporter stated that ‘minimum wage hikes actually punish low-wage employees’. Interestingly the magazine made no mention of the alternative approach being taken in the next door State. In 2011, seeing the contrasts between the economic policies run in the neighbouring states, Scott Walker declared that Wisconsin’s economy ‘would take off like a rocket’, as businesses relocated from Minnesota. He’s still waiting.
Data from US Labour Bureau | Minnesota | Wisconsin | National USA |
2010 – 2013 GDP growth | 7.5% | 4.5% | 6.1% |
Although the picture up to this point shows a clear victory for Dayton and Minnesota over Walker and Wisconsin, it may be too early to draw firm conclusions. The Financial Times quotes a Minnesota Chamber of Commerce representative saying that ‘companies in her state are looking to flee Minnesota’s higher taxes and increased regulations to move to Wisconsin… we hear about it almost daily’.
On the other hand Minnesota’s higher spending includes a new scheme of working tax credits. These are now helping 325,000 working families in the State, but it’s a bit early yet to find evidence that poverty is being reduced. By the next mid-term elections, in 2018, the full story will be clear.
Minnesota | Wisconsin | |||
Governor | Mark Dayton, Democrat | Scott Walker, Republican | ||
Economic policies | Expansionary; Progressively redistributive | Contractionary; Laissez faire | ||
Population size | 5.4m | 5.7m | ||
Restriction on movement of labour between states | None | None | ||
State Budget Surplus/Deficit 2014/15 (Nov 2014 figures) | +$1.1bn | -$2.2bn |
Sources: The Financial Times October 30th_ 2014; US Labour Bureau and other government and State data._
Questions (24 marks; 30 minutes)
Key concepts are at the end of this lesson.
-
Next year the minimum wage in Minnesota will be $9 an hour (£6) and in Wisconsin $7.25 (£4.80). Explain the possible economic impacts. (4 marks)
-
One of Mr Dayton’s policies has been to increase taxes on higher income groups. Using an AD/AS diagram illustrate the likely impact on the economy of Minnesota. (4 marks)
-
Discuss whether the reduction of poverty is a valid economic objective. (8 marks)
-
Discuss whether the State Budget figures shown in the summary table can be taken as proof of the superiority of the Keynesian policies undertaken in Minnesota over the austerity strategy of Wisconsin? (8 marks)
Key concepts for questions
Question 1 key concepts:
-
On the face of it, workers should head for Minnesota while firms head for Wisconsin, especially firms that are footloose (not tied to a location) and those that with labour intensive processes.
-
But despite the views of Forbes magazine, increases in minimum wage rates have always been met by howls from business leaders – but to no apparent effect in the marketplace; even if labour is 20% more in Connecticut than Wisconsin, few businesses would react to such a minor incentive; after all, no-one can know for how long this imbalance will last; is it worth closing a factory in Connecticut and moving to Wisconsin for the sake of what may prove a short-term difference in labour costs; the statistics provided in the article make it look as if jobs are not yet being lost in Mark Dayton’s state
Question 2 key concepts:
On the face of it an increase in taxes on any sector of society will push aggregate demand to the left; of course if the revenue generated is used to pay higher working tax credits, that would provide a compensating swing back to the right.
Question 3 key concepts:
Here is a question that seeks out a value judgement; but can the students find evidence to support their arguments? Here are some possible ones:
-
No, it’s a valid political argument but not an economic one. This argument is rooted in the view of economics taken by A level specifications, namely that economics is about scarcity rather than inequality. Broadly, there are only two ways to reduce poverty. The first is to redistribute resources from the better off to the less well off; economics is not in a good position to judge whether robbing Peter to pay Paul is ‘fair’. The second is to encourage economic growth which may benefit all sections of society, therefore including the poor; economic growth is unarguably a valid economic objective, but it’s hard to think that because growth is valid, poverty reduction is also valid.
-
Yes, it’s a valid economic argument. Even if some of the specifications treat inequality as an odd sideline to ‘real’ economics, it does actually appear in writing. Consequently it’s valid to assert that the reduction of poverty is a valid objective. After all, in a democracy economic objectives must be subject to the will of the people, and if Dayton was elected on a mandate to reduce poverty, it’s understandable that economic policy should be directed at that. Can economic policy actually achieve such an objective? Well unarguably yes – though it’s fair to argue a) that it might be at the expense of the better off and/or b) that it might be at the expense of overall output/GDP, due to the disincentive effects on the better off. But these are themselves sidelines to the central question about the validity of the policy.
Question 4 key concepts:
-
There is no doubt that at the time of writing (November 30th 2014) the evidence clearly points to the superiority of Minnesota’s Keynesian approach to the austerity strategy of Wisconsin; interestingly that superiority even extends to the fiscal balance, i.e. Minnesota’s ‘tax and spend’ approach has generated enough economic growth to provide the tax income to generate a budget surplus.
-
But as former Chinese leader Chou-en-Lai said when asked his view of the French Revolution (on the 200th anniversary of 1789), ‘It’s too early to say’. As of today Minnesota beats Wisconsin – but it may be that the picture will look different in a year or two’s time. Perhaps Wisconsin will start to prize employers away from the neighbouring state – benefiting its GDP at the expense of Minnesota’s.
-
But I doubt it. An alternative possibility is that Minnesota stays in a virtuous circle, with more businesses attracted by the growth and success of the economy. Certainly that would be true of service businesses, for whom there’s no real attraction in lower costs if you also have lower revenues. For manufacturers yes, higher unemployment is an attractive inward location signal; but can that really be the economic strategy here? Let’s create such a poor economic environment that manufacturers love it?
-
Is there yet ‘proof’ of the superiority of the Minnesota policies? No, it is too early. But the policies look very promising and within a couple of years some firm conclusions could be drawn from them.